Mar 062012
 
 March 6, 2012  Posted by at 4:14 pm Finance

John Vachon Woolworth May 1940 "Woolworth Company, Indianapolis, Indiana"

 

 

Since Lehman's failure in 2008, the name of the game has been to paper over deeply-rooted solvency issues in large institutions/countries with cheap liquidity. What helped keep markets afloat more than the liquidity itself, though, was the perception by the wealthiest segments of society that their solvency issues were being mitigated or resolved with a combination of loose fiscal/monetary policy and time. That perception was a more powerful and addicitng drug than the actual liquidity or promises of liquidity in the future.

Now, most big money managers are being forced to confront the fact that solvency issues are simply not going to disappear. That's what the Greek PSI debt restructuring scheduled for Thursday, the "success" of which still remains very uncertain, reflects more than anything else. It is the fact that a relatively large debtor is on the verge of default no matter what the PSI outcome is, and also that creditors will be forced into losses through collective action clauses if the uptake of Greece's offer is anything less than ubiquitous.

Although the direct losses from Greek bond holdings may be rather trivial at this point, the Greek government is just one within a long, inter-connected line of institutions that are utterly insolvent. It's default is something that most of the wealthy money shifters are not at all used to or prepared for. That is because the so-called "economic recovery" period of mid-2009 to early 2011 was only a recovery for those who have been concentrating wealth at the top for decades. For the rest of us, the prospect of default, bankruptcy and forced losses, whether we are talking losses in jobs, incomes, investments, social cohesion, etc., have been all too real.

 

2010: Recovering from the Great Recession  

In 2010, average real income per family grew by 2.3% (Table 1) but the gains were very uneven. Top 1% incomes grew by 11.6% while bottom 99% incomes grew only by 0.2%. Hence, the top 1% captured 93% of the income gains in the first year of recovery. Such an uneven recovery can help explain the recent public demonstrations against inequality. It is likely that this uneven recovery has continued in 2011 as the stock market has continued to recover. National Accounts statistics show that corporate profits and dividends distributed have grown strongly in 2011 while wage and salary accruals have only grown only modestly. Unemployment and non-employment have remained high in 2011.

 

incomegains

 

Almost all of those disproportionate gains for the top 1% in the U.S. have resulted from capital gains and corporate profits, which, in turn, are a result of global market valuations being propped up well above their 2009 lows and the relative value of the U.S. dollar being artificially suppressed. Needless to say, neither of those things have anything to do with easing credit burdens or creating jobs in the real economy aside from very short-term effects. Their primary effects are to both cocentrate more wealth and allow financial institutions to maintain very high levels of leveraged exposure to distressed debt-assets, such as Eurozone sovereign bonds.

As consumers pull back, workers are laid off and economies worldwide slow down or contract, the solvency issues for these institutions come back with a vengeance, except this time the fiscal backstops are virtually non-existent and the short-term liquidity measures are not nearly enough to paper over the liabilities. The fact is that even the central banks realize they no longer get any bang for their printed bucks, and that's why both the Fed and ECB have been downplaying their ability to continue providing liquidity in the future.

It is obvious to most that the first and second (perhaps last) LTROs by the ECB, in which an odd €600 billion in net 3-year loans was dished out to European banks, will only exacerbate solvency issues within the European periphery. In addition to creating stigma within bank funding markets, it has increased peripheral liabilities to the core and has drained available money supply from peripheral economies, as noted here. Another nice explanation of this insolvency dynamic is provided via "Sober Look", which also clears up a common misconception about the ECB deposit facility usage:

The issue with LTRO-II is not the spike in Deposit Facility

 

 

The mistake people often make is assuming that if banks were to lend these new euros out, the euros would leave the Deposit Facility. But any euro "created" by the ECB (via net new lending) has to end up in some bank's excess reserves (like the game of musical chairs). It may not be the same bank that took out the loan from the ECB, but it is still a bank within the Euro-system. So one way or another (whether banks, lend to each other, to clients, or buy securities) some bank in the Euro-system will end up with the excess reserves (net new euros never leave the system).

 

The issue with LTRO-II is therefore not the spike in the Deposit Facility. It is with the fact that Eurozone periphery (plus French and Belgian) banks end up using far more of the facility than banks from the "core" (particularly Germany). That has three effects:

 

1. It increases TARGET2 imbalances, with periphery central banks owing Bundesbank more money (as discussed here).

 

2. It creates a further imbalance in M3 money stock. Periphery banks use up the collateral previously employed for secured interbank borrowing (repo) to now post with the ECB against the LTRO loans. The collateral effectively leaves the system (and gets "trapped" at the periphery central banks for 3 years). A decline in repo borrowing among the banks in the periphery reduces broad money supply in these nations.

 

3. As more of the collateral, including retail and business loans (including ABS), that now qualifies for LTRO, is pledged to the ECB, any unsecured bonds that periphery banks still have outstanding will have zero recovery in case of default – since all the "good" assets have now been pledged (encumbered).

So that is what massive amounts of ECB liquidity gets you these days – greatly exacerbated solvency problems. These are not even long-term effects that only make themselves known a year or two later, but immediate effects that most mainstream analysts/publications (such as the FT or WSJ) are picking up on. Although QE3 is not really the same thing as LTRO, I guarantee the Fed is not looking at this European situation and jumping to the conclusion that more easing is needed right away, or that it could do anything to ease the systemic fear even if it was given the green light.

It's not that the liquidity spigot will be completely turned off, because it won't. Eventually, market valuations will decrease and the situation will become dire enough that little justification is needed for central banks to continue doing the only thing they are capable of doing. But, in the meantime, the perception that this liquidity (or monetization) can achieve the same effects it did 3 years ago will have diminished to the point that it doesn't matter either way. Liquidity or no liquidity, the big money managers will be scared to death of putting their dwindling capital at further risk.

And that will be in no small part due to the fact that, after this Thursday, the abhorred precedent of systemic debt default will have been set in the Eurozone. The Greek government, Troika and IIF have been doing everything they can to frighten hold out creditors into swapping their bonds, but they fail to understand what these big money investors are really afraid of. They are afraid that, even after the Greek deal is done and losses are absorbed, all of the debt floating around in the Eurozone will still be just as unsustainable as it was before; that it is only a matter of months before Portugal, Ireland, Spain and then Italy are clawing for more bailouts and similar restructuring deals; that Germany's economy will cave in as export benefits from keeping the EMU together are greatly outweighed by the monetary and socipolitical costs.

It is this fear that is currently weighing on markets and will continue to weigh on them until they reach significantly lower valuations. The truth is that, once this process gets going, no one is really quite sure where it will end up. Everyone has a large stake in this system, so it's not as if the big moneyed players will simply roll over and die without a fight. What's key to remember, though, is that many of them will be forced to pick their fights more carefully in the near future – to duck a few punches instead of leaning into every last one. They will have to learn to live with at least a portion of the reality that the rest of the world has been living with for years on end.

Home Forums Why Liquidity is No Longer Enough

  • This topic is empty.
Viewing 11 posts - 1 through 11 (of 11 total)
  • Author
    Posts
  • #8598
    ashvin
    Participant

    John Vachon Woolworth May 1940 "Woolworth Company, Indianapolis, Indiana"     Since Lehman's failure in 2008, the name of the
    [See the full post at: Why Liquidity is No Longer Enough]

    #1396
    Greenpa
    Participant

    “They are afraid that, even after the Greek deal is done and losses are absorbed, all of the debt floating around in the Eurozone will still be just as unsustainable as it was before; “

    Yup, I’m sure that’s part of it. I’m wondering though if some of those same players are not thinking “this is a mess; but maybe my best bet to save my own ass is to see to it that the credit default swaps are actually triggered; maybe I’ll collect more from JP Golem than I’ll ever get from Greece- before it all goes entirely to hell…”

    What’s your guess, Ash- how many are thinking that way? And oh, what a big FAT mess that would make.

    #1399
    ashvin
    Participant

    Greenpa,

    I’d say they’d be willing to be screwed on the CDS if they thought the PSI actually had a chance of making Greece’s public debts sustainable, and that the EFSF/ESM could actually contain the crisis for the rest of the periphery. But it’s plain as day that’s not going to happen, and so some of the holdouts figure “what the hell”, might as well try to recover some of the inevitable losses through litigation and CDS while there’s still any money left to recover.

    #1400
    el gallinazo
    Member

    The article was really interesting. It goes to show you how little most of the economic journalists really know what’s going down and how it works. Unfortunately, I found it a little confusing also, and I did go over the original Sober Look article. (Nothing worse than a sober look 🙂 It appears from the article that the ECB does not credit the banksters directly but through the national central banks? Actually, it might be useful if you could give a step by step chart of how the credit and collateral moves and why the new net amount must inevitably wind up in the ECB excess reserves. Why it must start its fateful voyage on the ECB (now bloated) balance sheet it clear.

    Regarding Greenpa’s comment:

    CDS’s are, of course, a zero sum game until the house of cards defaults start going down, i.e. the writers unable to pony up the dough and welching on their bets. The whole area is totally secretive since they are OTC and the last thing the writers wish is for other banks to know how vulnerable they are, as was AIG in 2008. However, it does seem that the Too Big to Jail banks wrote a lot more CDS’s than they bought, and a lot were purchased by hedge funds actually trying to hedge. Might have to revert back to beer to wash down the popcorn when this deal goes down.

    #1401
    YesMaybe
    Member

    I, too, am not at all clear about this:

    The mistake people often make is assuming that if banks were to lend these new eurit’sos out, the euros would leave the Deposit Facility. But any euro “created” by the ECB (via net new lending) has to end up in some bank’s excess reserves (like the game of musical chairs). It may not be the same bank that took out the loan from the ECB, but it is still a bank within the Euro-system. So one way or another (whether banks, lend to each other, to clients, or buy securities) some bank in the Euro-system will end up with the excess reserves (net new euros never leave the system).

    Could someone who’s in the know about this topic clear this up for us (as in whether claim made here is true or not and how the thingamabob works)?

    #1402
    ashvin
    Participant

    el gallinazo post=1000 wrote: Actually, it might be useful if you could give a step by step chart of how the credit and collateral moves and why the new net amount must inevitably wind up in the ECB excess reserves. Why it must start its fateful voyage on the ECB (now bloated) balance sheet it clear.

    Here is a better explanation of the process – https://soberlook.com/2012/01/deposit-facility-is-indicator-of-net.html

    The logic goes like this:

    Bank A borrows some cash from the ECB and posts some junk as collateral. The loan + junk is listed as an asset for the ECB, while the cash credited to the bank’s excess reserve account is listed as the liability. Bank A then transfers most of that credited cash to the ECB’s deposit facility, simply because it pays a slightly higher rate than holding it as excess reserves (although it has to keep some minimum amount as ER). If Bank A decides to use the money to make a loan to a bank, corporation or individual within the Eurozone, instead of keeping it on deposit with the ECB, the money will almost always end up being deposited in the excess reserve account of another bank within the EZ (assuming whoever ends up with the money doesn’t keep it in cash). Bank B will usually end up transferring to the ECB’s deposit facility for the same reason as the original bank.

    All of that being said, I don’t think the banks are actually lending out much of the money they borrow from the ECB. Some of LTRO1 was used for sub 3-year bonds of peripheral nations (perhaps longer if its an Italian bank lending to Italy), but probably not as much will be used from LTRO2. Mostly, they use it to pay off their own maturing bonds and keep it on deposit.

    #1404
    YesMaybe
    Member

    Thanks, Ash.

    But if they were to actually lend more money, wouldn’t a portion of the funds turn from “excess reserves” to “required reserves”? Like, say you inject $100, and the reserve ratio is 0.1. Then if the banks extend loans for $500, only $50 would end up in the deposit facility, right? Of course, I know that doesn’t happen immediately, but if it were to happen eventually then the use of the deposit facility should drop?

    #1409
    ashvin
    Participant

    YesMaybe,

    The ECB’s deposit facility is separate from the banks’ reserve accounts. Basically, each bank within the EZ has an option of storing their unused cash (credits) in their reserve account or in the DF.

    The Deposit Facility is an indicator of net borrowings from the ECB

    Banks generally keep the minimum amount necessary in the reserve account. They just want to make sure that the daily balances average out to a number that is above the minimum reserve requirement over a specific time period. This makes the reserve amount “cyclical”

    #1411
    Golden Oxen
    Participant

    Understanding Hieroglyphics is a breeze compared to this!

    #1412
    ashvin
    Participant

    ZH and Peter Tchir raise another way in which cheap LTRO liquidity makes solvency problems worse. The ECB’s requirement of variation margins on posted collateral creates the conditions for a “death spiral” in underlying asset markets if the collateral declines in value. Peripheral banks that receive margin calls from the ECB will generally have to sell assets (sovereign bonds) or pledge any remaining unencumbered assets, which makes it harder for peripheral governments to finance their deficits as well as the banks themselves, since it subordinates their unsecured creditors even further.

    https://www.zerohedge.com/news/ltro-scratching-surface

    Zerohedge pointed out a spike in additional collateral being posted at the ECB. According to some documents, the ECB is required to impose variation margins on its financing operations. This means that the collateral posted is not a one-time deal. If the collateral a bank has posted declines in value, the banks would have to post additional collateral. This is a big deal. Somehow the world seems to have an image that banks can borrow 3 year money at 1%, pledge an asset against it, and let the carry take effect with no other consequences. That is far from the truth if variation margins are being used.

    Having to post variation changes the product a lot. Buying longer dated bonds becomes very risky. They remain volatile and although banks could hold them in non mark to market books to avoid that volatility hitting their P&L, it wouldn’t save them from posting variation margin if the holdings decline in value. That helps explain why the curves are so steep, and really will limit the ability of banks to hold down longer term yields if we get another round of weakness, the death spiral risk is too scary.

    Portuguese banks should be of particular concern – again. The 2 year Portuguese bonds have jumped from a price in the low 80’s to the low 90’s. If banks bought these bonds as LTRO the potential for death spirals is on. As the bonds start declining in value, the banks would have to post collateral. Since the Portuguese banks are surviving almost exclusively on central bank money, their only choice would be to pledge some unpledged assets (if they have any), or sell the bonds and try and repay some of the LTRO. Selling bonds would put additional pressure on a then weak market. So the banks will pledge more assets. This does nothing to stop the slide in the underlying bonds, but would subordinate senior unsecured debt holders further. Senior unsecured debtholders will run for the hills again. They will see assets being taken out of the general pool – where they have a claim – and get shifted to the ECB, where ECB has the first rights.

    #1413
    Greenpa
    Participant

    Clean cup! Clean cup! Move down! Move down!

    🙂

Viewing 11 posts - 1 through 11 (of 11 total)
  • You must be logged in to reply to this topic.